Effective Altruism presents itself as an objective arbiter of where marginal resources can do the most good. Its framework emphasizes cause-neutrality and cost-effectiveness, aiming to direct support to whatever opportunities are most impactful at the current margin. Yet EA is also a movement with its own institutions, career paths, and organizational interests. This dual identity—as both impartial judge and institutional player—creates a fundamental tension that grows more acute as the movement expands.

This is best observed by zooming in on neglectedness. When EA is small, thinking on the margin poses no problem—individual EAs can freely direct their resources to whatever cause seems most compelling at the current margin. But as EA grows, any cause it champions becomes significantly less neglected. In theory, this is not a problem but a sign of success—solving problems quickly and effectively frees up bandwidth to look for the next problem to solve.. But as the movement grows larger, it will likely stand in the way of its own stated objectives.

Consider the fact that EA jobs are currently significantly oversubscribed.. Operations roles at EA organizations that pay well under $100,000 receive several hundreds, if not thousands of applications. EA orgs can afford long drawn-out evaluation processes spanning 3-6 months. Some in EA defend this oversubscription with arguments about power laws - claiming these roles are so much higher impact that the marginal value of an additional applicant doesn't diminish even with thousands of applicants.

But this seems implausible for most roles with bounded autonomy, even in exceptionally impactful organizations. The exceptions are high leverage roles like leading organizations or specialized technical positions. For a marketing manager or operations coordinator, it's hard to make the case that from a pool of 2000 qualified applicants, the delta between the best and second-best candidate justifies this insistence on working for an EA organization.

More importantly, this rationalization illustrates precisely how institutional forces can warp even well-intentioned movements. Even if we grant the power law argument, we should be wary of how conveniently it justifies the existing institutional structure. It's a perfect example of how EA organizations, despite their commitment to cause neutrality, can develop self-perpetuating logics that resist external scrutiny.

This points to a deeper challenge that EA faces through the lens of public choice theory. EA is not just a handful of grantmakers trying to allocate resources but also the social and intellectual capital of the movement. Consider how a substantial portion of EA's intellectual capital is now building careers in AI safety. These individuals, whether motivated by career advancement or genuine belief in the cause's importance, aren't immune to institutional incentives.

When you build a career in a specific domain, you naturally become slower to update downward on its relative importance. You see more arguments for its significance, develop deeper understanding of its complexities, and become better positioned to articulate why it matters. Even with purely altruistic motives, expertise breeds advocacy: "I understand this deeply now, so I need to make sure others appreciate its importance

This creates a form of intellectual and institutional lock-in. When EA identifies a cause area and invests in it, it's not just allocating money - it's creating careers, expertise, and institutional infrastructure. Any movement sufficiently large and invested in specific causes will face pressure to maintain these structures, potentially at the expense of pure cause neutrality.

One potential solution is to transform EA into a movement that primarily focuses on raising and allocating capital, rather than providing subsidized labor to "important causes." Under this model, EA would leverage market mechanisms and incentives to achieve its goals, with movement-building efforts centered on earning to give.

While some might object that ambitious EA projects require high-trust, value-aligned teams since impact can't be tracked purely through metrics, this argument deserves more scrutiny. Yes, corporations at the highest level have a clearer optimization target in profits, but at each lower level of hierarchy, they face the same challenges of incentive alignment and goodharting that EA organizations do. Despite this, good companies manage to build effective hierarchies and get important things done. EA could similarly harness incentives and competitive dynamics to its advantage.

The challenge facing EA isn't just theoretical—it's structural. As long as EA tries to be both an objective arbiter of impact and a builder of permanent institutions, it will face increasingly difficult tensions between these roles. The movement's future effectiveness may depend on choosing a clearer path: either embracing its role as an institution-builder with all the path dependencies that entails, or transforming into a lean capital allocator that can remain truly neutral about where resources should flow.

19

4
0

Reactions

4
0

More posts like this

Comments2
Sorted by Click to highlight new comments since:

I really liked this post, and found the second half of it especially insightful.

Executive summary: The Effective Altruism (EA) movement faces an inherent tension between its focus on neglected causes and its own growth, as increased attention to previously neglected areas makes them less neglected and potentially less impactful for new participants.

Key points:

  1. EA's success in attracting talent has led to severe oversubscription in EA jobs, challenging the assumption that these positions remain the highest-impact opportunities.
  2. The movement creates institutional lock-in through career paths and expertise development, making it difficult to maintain pure cause neutrality.
  3. EA organizations face public choice theory challenges as they build infrastructure and careers around specific cause areas.
  4. Proposed solution: EA could shift focus to primarily raising and allocating capital rather than providing subsidized labor, leveraging market mechanisms instead.
  5. Current model of requiring value-aligned teams may be unnecessarily restrictive, as corporations successfully handle similar incentive alignment challenges.

 

 

This comment was auto-generated by the EA Forum Team. Feel free to point out issues with this summary by replying to the comment, and contact us if you have feedback.

Curated and popular this week
Relevant opportunities